Relationships, Reciprocity and Exchange
in Societies XPS Version: PDF Version:MOBI Version:
by Bill Geddes 2 January 2010
Introduction
There is a constant ideological management of reality
in communities. Dominant groups ensure that the communities in which they live
are organized by and conform to the fundamental categorizations, classifications
and understandings which order their own thought and action. They reflexively
and subconsciously project these onto, and then attribute them to, features of
the real world and principles of its organization. That is, they
continuously and subliminally define and refine objective reality
for their community (this is what many of the ‘specialisms’ of Western
communities are about). Since they know how the world operates,
they also know the best ways in which life should be organized and lived.
They, therefore, feel responsible to ensure that people in the communities in
which they live conform to those understandings. This is ensured through the
many acculturative agencies and processes which can be found in any community of
human beings. These ensure that community organization and individual thought
and action conform to the community’s version of objective reality.
Education is a major acculturative force in Western
communities. One does not find Western style ‘education systems’ in non-Western
communities. Where non-Western countries have education systems they are modeled
on the systems developed in Western communities. Western education systems are
comprised of sets of powerful acculturative agencies, focused squarely on
ensuring that the most important fundamental understandings of Western
communities are understood and adhered to. Where they exist in non-Western
countries, education systems are essential elements of the hegemonic processes
and structures which Western countries insist non-Western countries must
‘develop’ and continuously monitor and regulate (to counter ‘poor educational
practice’) if they are to receive recognition and ‘aid’ from the West.
So, it should come as no surprise that some of the most
powerful theoretical models developed in Western academic and professional
circles incorporate and reaffirm the basic ideological understandings of Western
communities. Such models become unwitting tools in the hegemonic promotion of
Western capitalism. There is nothing fundamentally ‘wrong’ or reprehensible in
this, that is what dominant ideological communities do and have always done,
wherever they are found, and whatever their understandings of the world might
be. However, it is a problem for academic research and for anthropological
insight.
If we, as Westerners, are not aware that the most
‘convincing’ models will, almost inevitably, incorporate the central cultural
presumptions of Western capitalism then we are likely, unwittingly, in using the
models, to describe and explain phenomena we investigate in terms of similarity
to and deviation from Western forms, processes, behaviors and understandings.
Effectively, by default, we judge other cultural communities against Western
‘standards’ built into the theoretical models we employ, even as we claim that
we are trying to understand them in their own terms. Annette Weiner (1992), in
her book Inalienable Possessions: The Paradox of Keeping-While-Giving,
tackles this problem head on in examining the cultural baggage built into many
anthropological ideas and understandings. As she says,
… ethnographers do not record informants’ words as though on a
tabula rasa, but as modified by their own theories and perceptions honed on the
issues and arguments of previous anthropological discourses. How to get beneath
what historically we, as anthropologists, take most for granted and, in its
stead, hear what our field interpreters are actually saying is a major problem.
(1992 p. 24)
Weiner’s book examines some of the presumptions built into
the models of reciprocity and exchange which anthropologists have used in
‘explaining’ spheres of exchange in non-Western communities. A word of caution,
however, if you decide to read her book. I think that Weiner, showing how hard
it is to avoid this, has, herself, been caught in the very web she claims to
expose. The model she develops as an alternative to those she criticizes
contains similar ideological flaws. This is addressed by Mark Mosko (2000).
In this discussion we need to be alert to the problem. If we
build our own cultural assumptions into the models we use, we end up comparing
other cultural communities against the values and understandings of the
community to which we belong. That is not the job of anthropology. It might be
the task assigned to Western moralists (e.g. ‘human rights’ specialists), or to
those involved in the hegemonic expansion of Western capitalism (e.g. ‘Third
World Development’ specialists). However, anthropologists, if they are to study
humanity rather than be party to a hegemonic imposition of Western cultural
forms on the rest of the world, must attempt, to the degree that this is
possible, to understand communities and people in their own terms.
By definition, the economic models of capitalism are
ideological models which incorporate all the most basic presumptions about the
world and about human beings which are extant in Western communities. When
economic models are applied to life in non-Western communities they
automatically produce recommendations for change, since, inevitably, they
compare forms of organization and activity based on very different presumptions
against the forms and activities extant in Western communities. Recommendations
stemming from the application of these models are, all too often, used as the
base for ‘Third World development’ programs and projects.
In neo-classical economics (mainstream economics in Western
countries) three focuses are often employed in describing an economy. These are:
production, distribution and consumption. Here we will examine the processes of
distribution and the distributional constructs which become elaborated in
communities as people exchange goods and services, and as those exchanges are
integrated into community life and made ‘meaningful’.
Kinship studies were, at one time, of central importance in
most ethnographies. They have, over the past 50 years, become decreasingly
important in most ethnographic research. Sarah Franklin and Susan McKinnon
(2000), in an article entitled, ‘New Directions in Kinship Study: A Core Concept
Revisited’, explore why there has been declining interest in such studies. In
the process they present ideas from a range of disciplinary perspectives on the
ways in which kinship studies can be integrated into research within those areas
of study. Another study, by Christina Toren (1999), which focuses on present
relations between Fijians,
… shows how the ontogenetic process of constituting kinship as
intentionality makes any given Fijian able ideally to be kin with any other and,
further, makes kinship serve at once as the expression of collective order, as
the domain of relations in whose terms libidinal desire is structured, and as
the ground of ideas of self and other. An understanding of kinship has to be
constituted rather than merely received, and a key element in this process is a
developed consciousness of one's peers as peers. To become consciously a subject
of kinship, a child has to find its peers; in so doing it begins to know kinship
as the unifying and inexhaustible medium of all its relations with others. (1999
p. 265)
It is not only that people are born into kinship
relationships and understand themselves and others, and interact with their
worlds in terms of those relationships. It is also that people can use the
categories and processes of kinship to form structured relationships when they
need to do this. The ‘kinship system’ provides a model and ‘tool kit’ of
possible relationships which can occur between people. These can be used by
Fijians (and people in any community where kinship structures are dominant) to
structure and define relationships when they meet new people or begin
interacting with people in particular ways.
When anthropologists examine reciprocity and exchange in
non-Western communities they very often find themselves examining various forms
of kinship relations. On the other hand, when researchers focus on reciprocity
and exchange in Western communities, they find that kinship relations are of
minor significance. The focus is on independent individuals exchanging in terms
of benefits gained and losses incurred.
It is very easy to focus on material goods and visible
services as though they had an existence independent of the people amongst whom
they are observed and as though pursuit of them created the relationships
found between human beings. One might then attempt to classify and compare
different kinds of goods and services, trying to understand them as
self-existent items, and describe human relationships as the outcome of the
pursuit of particular kinds of goods and services. This has been very common in
social science theorizing.
However, in any community, the relationships between people
and the uses to which people put goods and services determine the ‘meaning’ and
significance of the goods and services. The goods and services are included in
human interaction, but are not the necessary cause of those interactions.
There cannot be a gift without a giver and a receiver, and the relationship
which exists between those involved determines both the gift and the nature of
the interaction which occurs.
As we study the nature of reciprocity and exchange, it is
important to remember that, among other things, one is focusing on the
tangible evidences of relationships between people. When one gives a
gift, one is saying something about one’s relationship with the other party to
observers, to the recipient and, of course, to oneself. This is not only true in
giving gifts. Each act of borrowing, lending, buying, selling, bartering,
taking, giving, begging, stealing, creating, destroying…, carries in it
the nature of the relationship which the participants perceive as existing
between them and between each of them and their environments (however
defined).
To understand reciprocity and exchange, and, ultimately, all
forms of distribution of goods and services in any community, one must
understand the relationships which exist between individuals and groups in the
community. And relationships, in turn, reflect the forms of classification and
categorization in the community. Once I know ‘where you fit’ in relation to me,
I will know how to behave toward you and I will know the appropriate forms of
reciprocity and exchange in which we should engage. Anthropologists have often
reported being given kinship position in the communities they have worked in.
They are declared to be ‘sons’ or ‘daughters’, ‘brothers’ or ‘sisters’ or
declared to have some other kinship relationship to community members. Once this
happens, people can begin interacting with them ‘as though’ they were what they
have been declared to be (see Christina Toren (1999)). This is why starting
ethnographic research by looking at the ways in which goods and services are
transferred between individuals and groups will soon lead you to an examination
of all forms of relationship within the community.
In most of the social sciences, it is presumed that the
relationships which exist between individuals ‘emerge’ from the processes of
exchange in which they engage. Human beings, it is assumed, are first and
foremost ‘actors’ and the social relationships in which they are involved are
outcomes of self-interested activity. So, exchange comes first, and groups
emerge from those exchanges. Because they are convinced of the importance of
reciprocity and exchange in understanding community organization and
interpersonal interaction, theorists in the social sciences have attempted to
define the nature of exchange. There have been two directions in which these
attempts at definition have gone.
The most common direction has been toward a single definition
of exchange. This has been encapsulated most clearly in economic models
of exchange, but has been replicated in a range of social models developed out
of social exchange theory.
The second direction has been toward
defining exchanges contextually. This approach has assumed that the nature of
exchanges is determined by the nature of the relationships perceived as existing
between those involved in exchange. There cannot be a single definition of
exchange. Rather, the characteristics of exchange depend on the context in which
it occurs.
The presumptions about the nature of
individuals and communities of human beings upon which these two approaches base
their reasoning are very different.
Mark Bosco (2000) provides a response to Annette Weiner’s
(1992) book on the ethnocentric presumptions built into forms of exchange and
reciprocity used in anthropological studies. The account starts from a
presumption that the reader will be familiar with Weiner’s writing, but it deals
with issues which can be understood in their own right.
Weiner claims that life is full of ‘duplicities and
ambiguities that create tensions that can only be ameliorated and never
resolved.’ (1992 p. 5) Processes of exchange are predicated on these tensions.
In fact,
Exchange acts fuel these tensions because all exchange is
predicated on a universal paradox – how to keep-while-giving… The
motivation for keeping-while-giving is grounded in… the need to secure
permanence in a serial world that is always subject to loss and decay… Even
small groups expend enormous efforts and resources, for example, to convince the
younger generation to beware of loss, to preserve relationship, and to guard
sacred possessions… The paradox inherent in the process of keeping-while-giving
creates an illusion of conservatism, of refashioning the same things, of status
quo. (1992 pp. 5, 7, 8)
According to Weiner, while people need to transfer goods,
services and information between each other to communicate, to sustain
relationships, and to obtain other things they need, they feel as though they
are losing something important whenever they do so. They are, therefore,
impelled to attempt, in some way or other, to restore the status quo, to ‘keep’
what they are ‘giving’. Mark Mosko is less than convinced by this explanation of
the nature of exchange. This is a variant of social exchange theory, which we
will examine shortly. It suggests that people are involved in ‘cost/benefit’
analysis coupled with an inherent human drive to conserve possessions.
Mosko, writing for an audience of anthropologists, presumes
that his readers will have a great deal of ethnographic information at their
finger-tips. However, the article does introduce us to the confrontation between
social exchange theory and studies based on typologies of reciprocity. Weiner
espouses the first position, Mosko the latter. This is not a new argument. In
anthropology it went under the name of the ‘formalist/substantivist’ debate for
many years and is now resurfacing rather more diffusely as an argument about the
primacy of exchange or structure in the fashioning of human relationships.
Despite years of controversy in anthropological circles,
there is still a clear division between theorists who view persons as ‘unitary,
bounded individuals rather than divisible or partible beings’ (Mosko 2000 p.
377), and those who believe that to understand individuals and their behavior
you must understand the ways in which they are integrated within the communities
in which they live.
The approaches to reciprocity and exchange which we are going
to examine next illustrate this divide. They are presumed, by those who promote
them, to provide a framework for understanding human interaction and the
relationships in and through which they occur.
In Western communities, it is commonly believed that we are
all, at heart, pre-social, independent, self-interested, self-promoting,
competitive and acquisitive beings, intent on conserving and expanding our
possessions and furthering our own well-being and independence, if necessary, at
the expense of others around us. There has been a range of models of ‘social
exchange’ developed through the 19th and 20th centuries
which are founded on these assumptions. These presumptions provide the base for
most economic and social models of exchange. According to social exchange
theorists (whom you will meet in various guises in most social science
theorizing) all exchange is based on the acquisitive, competitive, and
self-interested drives of human beings who want to be independent.
According to this model, if you and I were in an exchange
relationship it would be because you perceived me as having something you want
(a good grade?) and I perceive you as having something I want (your money?). I
look for ways of getting as much money as I can out of you while giving you as
little as possible of what ‘belongs’ to me (I want to ‘conserve’ what is mine).
You look for ways of getting the best grade you can out of me for the lowest
price. The relationship might look like one of cooperation – teacher and student
in the pursuit of knowledge – but it is, in reality, competitive, with each of
us pursuing our own, independent, self-interested goals. Our relationship will
continue for only so long as I can convince you to keep giving me money and you
can convince me to keep passing you! Once we see the other as having nothing to
offer (you run out of money – I run out of units you want to do) the
relationship ends. You might recognize Weiner’s paradox of keeping-while-giving
in all this.
The development of education in most Western countries, over
the past couple of decades, has largely been driven by this caricature of
human motivation and sociability, with educational institutions becoming
primarily ‘profit making’ organizations and education being promoted as a
‘commodity’ or ‘consumable’. In the process, communities have devalued education
as a cooperative pursuit of understanding and emphasized its value as a
preparation for entry into the world of competitive wealth attainment. If it
doesn’t lead to money, what’s the point? Not, of course, that you and I have
such a crass view of the value of education!
Edward Lawler and Shane Thye (1999 p. 217) describe the
model,
Social exchange theory assumes self-interested actors who
transact with other self-interested actors to accomplish individual goals that
they cannot achieve alone. Self-interest and interdependence are central
properties of social exchange. Whether it is two lovers who share a warm and
mutual affection, or two corporations who pool resources to generate a new
product, the basic form of interaction remains the same. Two or more actors,
each of whom has something of value to the other, decide whether to exchange and
in what amounts.
Social exchange theory shares a great deal of common ground
with rational action theory and cost benefit analysis. Their roots
can be found in the Western philosophy of utilitarianism 1.
The approach, with minor variations in emphasis and definition, is also
sometimes referred to as rational choice, the problem of collective
action, research in ‘micro fundamentals,’ or methodological
individualism. In anthropology it is also known as formalism, in
contrast to the substantivism of Karl Polanyi and those who have
developed his ideas over the past fifty years. Agnar Helgason and Gisli Palsson
(1997), in an article entitled ‘ Contested commodities: the moral landscape of
modernist regimes’, examine some of the controversies which still exist between
anthropologists who adopt a formalist (social exchange) approach to exchange and
anthropologists who adopt a substantivist approach. We will examine Polanyi’s
ideas shortly.
Lawler and Thye’s (1999) article both accepts the validity of
the model and reviews the literature on social exchange theory. It provides an
excellent illustration of the ways in which Western ideological understanding
becomes unconsciously built into Western ‘explanatory’ models and a reminder
that social science theorizing is not acultural. The ways a theorist sees his or
her world, and the basic presumptions about life which are held to be
self-evident are usually either explicitly or implicitly written into the
theoretical constructs which theorists build.
Social exchange theory presumes that individuals interact in
terms of competitive self interest. Their interactions are focused by both
social incentives to behave in particular socially approved ways and
social constraints on ‘unacceptable’ behavior (social ‘benefits’ and
‘costs’). Those incentives and constraints have been developed over time as a
consequence of individuals’ experiences in the competitive cut and thrust of
getting what they feel they need and want. They channel activity to minimize the
costs and maximize the gains of interaction for the greatest number in the
community (it is in this that the model draws most heavily on utilitarian
ideas - the ideal community is, therefore, ‘democratic’). In these ways,
ostensible cooperation between individuals and groups emerges and a
variety of communal structures develop to further what are, ultimately,
individual, self interested activities aimed at meeting individual needs and
wants in an environment of competitors and scarce resources. The innate traits
of human beings turn out to be remarkably similar to those of individuals as
defined in Western industrialized communities.
Claude Levi-Strauss (1963, pp. 279ff), an anthropologist
writing during the 1940s to 1980s, made a distinction between what he called
‘home-made’ models of social interaction and organization, and models designed
to uncover the basic presumptions and principles upon which social life is
constructed. Home made models perpetuate the phenomena they claim to
explain. Explanatory models elucidate the fundamental presumptions and
principles upon which social life is built. Although those who employ the
conscious, home made models will claim that their use ‘explains’ social
phenomena, in fact, they are part of the ideological acculturative process. The
use of the models reaffirms and reinforces the behaviors, attitudes and
understandings which they are supposed to ‘explain’. According to Levi-Strauss,
conscious models… are by definition very poor ones since
they are not intended to explain the phenomena but to perpetuate them. Therefore
structural analysis is confronted with a strange paradox well known to the
linguist, that is: the more obvious structural organization is, the more
difficult it becomes to reach it because of the inaccurate models lying across
the path which leads to it. (1963, p. 282)
As you have already seen in Mosko’s (2000) article, many
anthropologists are wary of models which employ a singular definition of the
nature of social exchange such as that presented in social exchange theory.
However, theoretical models which either explicitly or implicitly rely on this
set of assumptions about human interaction are very common in social science
theorizing.
For researchers and theorists who espouse a variant of social
exchange theory, individual human beings are primary. Social organization and
social interaction – exchange networks 2
- are outgrowths of individual human beings trying to fulfill their own
needs and wants and ensure their status as independent individuals. So,
individual human beings, and the relationships they form in the process of
achieving their independent goals come first. Change the needs and wants of
individuals and they will change their interactions and, consequently, the
social structures which have emerged to facilitate the pursuit of their
independent ends. In the words of George Homans who wrote widely from this
perspective in the mid 20th century,
… elementary social behaviour, pursued
long enough by enough people, breaks through the existing institutions and
replaces them. Probably there is no institution that was not, in its germ,
elementary social behaviour. (Homans, 1961 p. 1)
Social structures and institutions emerge from the
interactions of independent individuals pursuing their own private ends. The
relative statuses of people and the relative power they exercise are also
derived from these relationships, driven by people trying to ensure that they
retain any advantages they have in the exchange process. Linda Molm, Gretchen
Peterson and Nobuyuki Takahashi (2001) sum up the relative power positions of
human beings in interacting groups like this:
The concept of dependence is pivotal to
the theory's analysis of power. Each actor's power derives from the other's
dependence: A's power over B increases with B's dependence on A, and vice versa
(Emerson 1972a, 1972b). Inequalities in power and dependence create power
imbalanced relations, in which the less dependent actor has a power advantage
over the more dependent, disadvantaged actor. The theory distinguishes between
power as a structural potential, determined by actors' relations of dependence,
and power use as the resulting inequality in benefits obtained by more and less
powerful actors in a relation or network. The former affects the latter, in that
imbalances in power tend to produce corresponding inequalities in exchange
benefits.
Because power is a function of
dependence, predicting power and its use requires identifying variables that
affect actors' relative dependencies. (Molm et al 2001 p. 259)
According to social exchange theory, if two people are in an
exchange relationship, the person most committed to making the relationship work
is in a disadvantageous position. That person will have put more ‘resources’
into making the relationship a success than the other person and so the ‘costs’
and ‘benefits’ of the relationship vary inversely to the commitment of the
participants. The one who is more committed will have to ‘pay’ more than the
other party to maintain the relationship – they become relatively more
‘dependent’ on the relationship. People who are in ‘relationships of dependence’
feel subservient to those on whom they depend and so, inevitably, human beings
dream of independence, of not having to rely on others for their needs and
wants.
Social exchange theory presumes that human action is
primary and that social structures and institutions emerge out of human
interaction and are finally sustained by it. But what if human action is
instituted by the structures of the community? Then the forms of interaction
which occur will be determined by the forms of organization and by the ways
people are brought up to behave through their placement within the social whole.
Community structures will be primary and human interaction and exchange will
reflect the ways in which communities are organized.
This was the focus of a great deal of Marxist theorizing 3 of the late 19th and 20th
centuries. Human beings, Karl Marx believed, behave as they are brought up to
behave, determined by the ways in which their society is organized and
articulated to the material environment, that is, the ‘relations of production’
which exist in the society. In his own words,
In the social production of their existence, men inevitably enter
into definite relations, which are independent of their will, namely relations
of production appropriate to a given stage in the development of their material
forces of production. The totality of these relations of production constitutes
the economic structure of society, the real foundation, on which arises a legal
and political superstructure and to which correspond definite forms of social
consciousness. The mode of production of material life conditions the general
process of social, political and intellectual life. It is not the consciousness
of men that determines their existence, but their social existence that
determines their consciousness. (1859 p. 1)
Marx, a Western person, assumed that ‘relations of
production’ would be central to the ways in which people are defined and
interact. The self-interested, competitive, acquisitive individualism of Western
communities is an inevitable consequence of the stage they have reached ‘in the
development of their material forces of production’. It is instilled in people
through their upbringing. Capitalist societies require self-interested,
competitive individualism and so people are brought up to display those
characteristics in their interactions. In other societies, people will be
trained to behave in ways required by the dominant ‘relations of production’ of
their communities. Economic exchange is the kind of exchange required for
capitalism to work.
Marx was a thinker of his time, and an optimist. He was
convinced that human societies were evolving toward a particular set of
‘relations of production’. There would be a final structuring of society
reached, where human beings would fully understand the productive potential of
their environments and would harness that potential for the greatest good of
each individual in the society. Individuals would, ‘naturally’, be brought up to
behave in ways required by the dominant relations of production, ensuring that,
at last, each person would contribute what he or she was able to the social
whole and receive what he or she needed. This is the meaning of the term
‘communism’.
Karl Polanyi, an economic historian writing in the middle of
the 20th century was strongly influenced by Marxist ideas, but less
than convinced about the evolutionary direction of human development. He argued
that,
the term economic, as commonly used to describe a type of
human activity, is a compound of two meanings. … The first meaning, the formal,
springs from the logical character of the means-end relationship … from this
definition springs the scarcity definition of economic. The second, the
substantive meaning, points to the elemental fact that human beings, like all
other living things, cannot exist for any length of time without a physical
environment to sustain them; this is the origin of the substantive definition
of economic. The two meanings… have nothing in common. (1977 p. 19)
On one hand, there is an economy as
defined in economic theory and as experienced in Western communities. This
economy works best if people behave as self-interested, competitive, acquisitive
individuals because it is a ‘market’ economy. People are brought up to behave in
ways which will ensure their success in such an environment. Polanyi argued that
the particular ways in which human beings utilise their material environments
and the forms of relationships through which goods and services are distributed
throughout the society, are not derived from innate individual human traits and
instincts and are not ‘natural’ consequences of exploiting material environments
(it was in this assertion that he parted company with Marxists). Rather, the
ways in which people behave and the ways in which they use their material
environments are determined by the ways in which their communities are
organised.
He claimed that there is an
economistic fallacy, which ‘consists in a tendency to equate human
economy with its market form.’ (1977 p. 20) The substantive economy in
any community, he argued, is embedded in the organization and
interactions of the community. So, exchange relationships are determined
by the structure of the community rather than the structure of the community
being determined by exchange relationships. To demonstrate that not all economic
activity is organised like a Western market economy he described the economic
activities of ancient historical Mesopotamian communities, showing that they
were very differently organised. He labelled the system he described a
redistributive system.
Redistribution stands for a movement towards a centre and out of
it again, whether the objects are physically moved or only the disposition of
them is shifted. (1977 p. 36)
He claimed that in communities which
are organised with a wide peasant base and a hierarchical leadership structure,
goods and services initially flow from the peasant base upward through the
hierarchy. If you examined the system at some periods it would appear that there
was a systematic exploitation of the peasant base by the elite of the community.
However, it is the task of the elite not merely to use the surpluses they
receive, but to provide a range of services and to store and redistribute
surplus production to community members who are in need. So, if you examined the
system from the perspective of the elite or during times of hardship, you would
find that there was a reverse flow occurring. Goods and services would be
flowing from the centre out toward the peasant base. To understand how such an
economy worked one had to understand the organization of the society, not merely
individual exchanges. What might be seen as an exploitative system from either
perspective, could be shown to be a ‘social welfare’ system when one looked at
the long-run activities of all members of the community.
Polanyi’s challenge to economic theory
was based on his claim that there are forms of exchange of goods and services
which do not conform to the definition of exchange which is used in economic and
social exchange theory. So, it was a fallacy to claim that economic and social
exchange models could be applied universally. This was a fairly rudimentary
attack on the universal validity of social exchange theory, but it was a start.
Polanyi’s models did not explain why different communities had different
forms of redistribution and exchange, only that it could empirically be shown
that this was the case. It remained for someone to provide a model of exchange
relationships which would spell out why it was possible to have such different
forms of community organization and interpersonal exchange.
The next major contribution to the
debate came from Marshall Sahlins. Although Sahlins’ model of exchange
relationships provides a way forward, it does not directly deal with the kinds
of exchange Polanyi described. Rather, it describes forms of exchange between
people who are roughly equal in status within a community. Polanyi introduced a
focus on hierarchically structured exchange relationships, the ways in which
goods and services moved through political and social hierarchies. Sahlins was
more concerned with the ways in which kinship and social distance influenced
exchange relationships. He explains this in his most influential book on the
subject, Stone Age Economics, when he says,
Rank difference as much as kinship distance supposes an economic
relation. The vertical, rank axis of exchange – or the implication of rank – may
affect the form of the transaction, just as the horizontal kinship-distance axis
affects it. (1972 p.206)
Polanyi’s redistributive system is one
focusing on exchange between people of different rank (the ‘vertical, rank axis
of exchange’). Sahlins’ model of reciprocity and exchange focuses on the
horizontal axis: the ways in which the nature of exchange differs with the
degree to which people see themselves as ‘related’ to each other, coupled with
the amount they have to do with each other.
Some anthropologists have examined a
range of ‘spheres’ of exchange 4, usually meaning that there
are exchange complexes which are focused within particular organizational areas
of a community. As Frederick Damon (1993 p. 243) describes for the U.S.A.,
there are spheres of gifts, of wage labor, and of productive and
financial capitals. It is easy to show that each operates by different
principles with different purposes. It is also easy to show – requiring only a
book or two – that complex patterns of reciprocal dependencies, with painful
contradictory consequences, govern their interactions.
Damon goes on to describe similar
spheres of exchange for a community involved in Kula exchange. We will examine
Kula exchange more closely shortly. You need to remember, when examining
Sahlins’ model of exchange relationships, that he is dealing with one of the
spheres of exchange which exist within communities. The nature of reciprocity
and exchange become much more complex in Sahlins’ typology than they appear when
one examines simple interactions between two individuals in face to face
relationships as in social exchange theory.
The key to understanding Sahlins’
contribution to the debate on the nature of exchange is that he, following
Polanyi’s lead, envisaged more than one definition of an exchange relationship.
He concluded that the kind of exchange relationship which would be found between
two individuals or groups was determined by the nature of the relationship which
existed between them. There are many possible definitions of exchange, since
particular instances of exchange and reciprocity are individuated
expressions of relationships which exist between categories of people.
This points us directly to the kind of
model which Levi-Strauss (1963) called a ‘structural’ model, based on the
unconscious principles of categorization and classification which exist within
any ‘structured’ community. One can understand exchanges best when one realises
that they are visible expressions of the kinds of relationship which people
perceive as existing between themselves, making them into a community of
human beings.
The relations which people perceive as
existing between themselves are a sub-set of the relations which occur within
and between the classificatory categories of thought which each member of a
community learns from his or her community from the moment of birth. You can’t
‘think’ without such a classificatory structure since thought is a process of
comparison to determine similarities and differences between perceived items
(and that is the definition of classificatory categorization). These
relations of similarity and difference are expressed in all forms of structured
communication between people, from language to the exchange of material goods
and services.
The classificatory categories of any
community have been unconsciously developed over the history of the community
and so will be unique to that community. Yet, because there is a finite set of
relations which can occur between elements in a structure, there will be many
apparent similarities between communities. We can’t pursue this further here,
but, in formal system analysis it is recognised that there is a variety
of kinds and combinations of relationship which can exist between elements of a
structure. As the Encyclopaedia Britannica puts it,
Each formal system has a formal language composed of primitive
symbols acted on by certain rules of formation (statements concerning the
symbols, functions, and sentences allowable in the system) and developed by
inference from a set of axioms. (“formal system" Encyclopædia Britannica
Online. <http://search.eb.com.au/bol/topic?thes_id=153894> [Accessed
11 February 2002].)
Since human beings are sentient and
capable of reflexive thought, they do not merely conform to the structural
requirements of the system in which they live. They are able, individually, to
focus on, and compare and contrast the forms of relationship they are involved
in and so experiment with alternative definitions of, and behaviours in
structured interactions. That is, they individuate their social
relationships, just as they do every facet of their experience and
understanding. This is what Mosko is referring to when he says,
Melanesian persons are best understood, not as the
‘indivisible’ unitary beings of Western jurisprudence but as ‘dividual’ or
‘partible’ agents who, in seeming to exchange objects with one another, detach
and attach respective parts of persons… (2000 p. 381)
People are constantly defining and
redefining themselves in their interactions. The structure is, necessarily,
conservative, but it is neither static nor completely prescriptive.
Sahlins points to this when he says
that,
it is not only that kinship organises community, but communities
kinship, so that a spatial, coresidential term affects the measure of kinship
distance and thus the mode of exchange (1972 p. 197).
While, in many communities, exchanges
are formally structured by kinship relationships, kin who live close to each
other develop closer relationships than kin living at a distance. This results
in different forms of exchange developing between an individual and two or more
kin who might share the same kinship relationship with him or her but live
closer or further away. However, the set of relationships from which they build
their individuated interactions is already spelt out in the social structures of
their community. This is the point of Christina Toren’s (1999) discussion of the
ways in which Fijian kinship relations pattern interactions between people in
Fiji. As she says,
A Fijian village child lives kinship as the very medium of
existence; such a child constitutes ideas of self and others or, in simpler
terms, comes to be who he or she is, in reciprocal relations between kin. (1999
p. 265)
Sahlins is suggesting that the forms
of reciprocity which will be observed will take their character from the forms
of social relationship which exist between exchangers as members of a structured
community. And, in turn, the social relationships which exist between the
exchangers will depend on the number and kind of relationships summed up in each
person. People are nodes of relationships and their interaction with each
other person or group is ‘flavoured’ by the blend of relationships in which they
are involved.
If you stop for a moment and think of
yourself. You ‘know’ who you are by the way you relate to everything around you.
All the perceived relationships between yourself and all the recognised elements
of your environments, provide the raw material from which you construct your
self-image. If someone tries to change those perceived relationships, that
person assails your self-image. You, inevitably, react to defend your definition
of yourself. That is, you try to conserve your present definition by
conserving present recognised relationships.
A short-hand way of determining
how a person defines himself or herself is to ask him or her to tell you ‘who’
someone else is. Then, listen to what they focus on as important in defining the
person.
Human beings, born into communities,
are taught that certain forms of relationship are important, and so, in any
community, one will find that some kinds of relationship are emphasised more
than others. In Western communities many individuals are taught that
competitively balanced exchange is important and that each individual should
value privacy, independence, and material possessions. Relationships tend to
take their ‘flavour’ from these values. As we will see shortly, not all
communities see these values as important.
To understand an act of exchange one
has to understand the relationship which the participants in the exchange
perceive as existing between them. The form of an exchange between family
members will be different to the form of an exchange between strangers (and
different to the forms of exchange found between people of variant rank or
status in the community). A guide to understanding the ways in which exchange
relationships differ, with categorization between people within ‘spheres’ of
exchange in communities, can be gained by considering reciprocity and exchange
as occurring on a continuum of relationship as below:
In using this model, you need to
remember that you are dealing with a continuum of relationships, not just
three different relationships. As you move from left to right along the line,
the relationship is progressively based on perceiving fewer similarities and
more differences between participants in an exchange 5.
The resulting exchange behaviour takes its flavour from those perceptions and so
varies as you move along the line.
The more two people see themselves as
‘related’, that is, as sharing a common identity, the more they will emphasise
sharing rather than holding sets of separate possessions. So, when one person
wants something the other has, they will tend to assume the right to take it and
use it, rather than having to ‘ask permission’ or ‘buy’ it from the other
person. Generalised reciprocity is a very common form of exchange within nuclear
family groupings. There are many possessions that belong to the household rather
than to the individuals in the household. Members use them when they need to
without having to ask permission of other family members. The item might be in
the possession of one of the members, but it can be taken and kept by another
member until someone else needs it.
Degrees of similarity and
difference between people are contextually defined. I might emphasise my
‘difference’ from other family members when acting inside the home. I might
emphasise ‘similarity’ to my family members when we are acting as a unit in a
wider setting. And, perhaps, I, my family, the family of my uncle and/or my aunt
might act as a unit in a still wider setting. So, depending on the context, I
might well behave differently toward members of those groups at different times.
Sometimes I will emphasise our differences, by insisting that some things are
’mine’ and others are ‘theirs’. But, sometimes, in different contexts, we will
emphasise our similarity, finding it much easier to ‘share’ things with each
other. I’m sure you can think of times when you were with a wider group and
presumed that you could use things the group had which you would never presume
to use if you were not part of the ‘same’ group.
The less interacting people see
themselves as sharing the same identity, the more differences they will
recognise as existing between them. This will make it more likely that they will
have to ask permission to use an item in the other person’s possession. As the
differences increase, they will increasingly feel the need to ‘balance’ the
relationship by offering something to the other person in exchange for the item
they want to use. The people involved will tend to hold separate sets of
possessions and feel that they are ‘losing’ something when an item they have is
given to the other person (there is a conservation principle at work).
By the time we reach the mid point on
the diagram above, there is a feeling that when something is given to one
person, the other should get something of fairly equal value in return. The
exchange should be ‘balanced’. In most forms of exchange to the left of the
diagram, the people involved in exchange feel themselves to be in some degree
related to each other and are not interested in making a ‘profit’ at the expense
of those with whom they associate. The more closely they consider themselves to
be integrated with each other, the more complete the sense of sharing
possessions among them becomes. Exchanges on the left side of our diagram tend
to reinforce social relationships based on similarity and often seem
deliberately designed to do this.
The ‘balanced reciprocity’
relationship is most commonly found between acquaintances rather than friends,
people who are considered connected with us in some way, but are very definitely
not members of our ‘in-group’. Neighbours in Western communities are often in
this kind of relationship. One doesn’t feel that it is right to make a profit
out of them, but exchanges should be balanced and when something is lent or
borrowed it should fairly promptly be returned.
As we move to the right of the
diagram, people who interact with each other emphasise their differences rather
than their similarities. The less like each other they consider themselves to
be, the more they emphasise keeping their own possessions and trying to get
yours for as little cost as possible (Weiner’s ‘keeping-while-giving’
relationship). If you have this kind of relationship with another person you
have no problem in ‘buying’ and ‘selling’ items. If you try to buy and sell to
people on the left side there is an uneasy feeling that this is not the
appropriate thing to do.
This is one important reason why many
business activities in close knit communities fail. Outsiders do much better at
business because they can buy and sell without resentment developing in the
community as a result of their activities. Of course, by engaging in competitive
exchange they are also cementing their definitions as ‘outsiders’. This can be a
trap for researchers engaged in ethnographic research. If you ‘pay’ for
information, you are going to get the kind of information people tell
‘outsiders’. You are, at the same time, ensuring that they categorise you as an
outsider.
In any community one will find all
forms of reciprocity. It is not that in some communities one finds
generalised reciprocity and in other communities one finds balanced or negative
reciprocity. Rather, in every community one will find people who are closely
defined as similar to each other and others who will be less closely related.
And all these relationships are, of course, relative to the person on whom
attention is being focused. One will also find people living in neighbouring
communities or on the fringes of communities who are defined as primarily
different from community members. Expect to find that the forms of exchange
which occur will reflect the relationships perceived as existing between people.
They will also, in quite different ways, reflect the status, rank and prestige
differences which are perceived between people.
It is time to examine ethnography. The
aim in the next three sets of ethnographic writings you will be examining is to
introduce you to some of the forms of reciprocity and exchange which are found
within communities. These writings provide information on a number of different
focuses or ‘spheres’ in exchange. First, there are the day to day exchanges and
interactions which occur between people in supplying their needs and wants and
in smoothing their relationships with each other. Second, there are exchange
complexes which are clearly focused on status attainment, status maintenance and
the challenging of statuses in the communities. Third, there are exchanges which
seem to focus on relationships between groups, providing means for maintaining,
challenging and reassessing the relative positions of leaders and the groups
which they represent.
Perhaps the most famous description of
processes of reciprocity and exchange within a society is Bronislaw Malinowski’s
(1977) description of kula exchanges in the Trobriand Islands of Papua
New Guinea. The exchange network that he describes in that brief article still
exists in the present, though it has altered considerably in response to the
enormous pressures for change which the people of the island group have
experienced since Malinowski wrote his description in the early 1920s.
In his description of exchange
on Normanby Island, Carl Thune focuses on the ‘specific way it is tied to and
grounded within a local village world of exchange strategies and transactions
between related matrilineages’ (1983 p. 345).
Thune’s ethnographic account of the
structure of village and Kula exchange on Normanby Island provides a lot of
information on a range of forms of reciprocity and exchange. It shows how the
context in which exchanges take place determines whether a larger or smaller
group is included in the ‘sharing’ of goods, and how competitive exchange is
similarly contextually determined. Sometimes the susu is the important
basic unit, sometimes it is the kasa. And sometimes it is the larger
village which people see as the basic unit in which they are united with the
other members in a sharing relationship. People outside the recognised unit,
‘trade’ and ‘barter’, that is, engage in various forms of ‘balanced’ exchange
(sometimes competitive, sometimes not) with unit members.
The Potlatch System, as famous in
anthropological literature as the Kula Ring, was first described by Franz
Boas(1966) at the beginning of the twentieth century. Stuart Piddocke (1965)
sketches the main elements of the system after providing a brief ethnographic
contextualisation of the information. Anthropologists have often attempted to
explain non-Western forms of exchange in Western economic terms. In his opening
paragraph Piddocke says, ‘the potlatch had a very real pro-survival or
subsistence function, serving to counter the effects of varying resource
productivity’. Stanley Walens (1981) provides a very different picture of the
nature of the potlatch system.
Piddocke focuses very strongly on the
ways in which the Kwakiutl manage and utilise their resources, a distinctively
Western set of concerns. Walens (1981) provides a very different focus. He
argues that,
It is impossible to understand Kwakiutl culture, and the
structure and meaning of Kwakiutl behavior, without first understanding their
basic ontological system [the system through which they structure nature and
relations of existence] and the principles of causality on which it is based.
These causal principles delineate the organization and operation of the physical
world and man’s role in affecting events and their outcome. (1981 p. 21)
Walens insists that systems of
reciprocity and exchange like those of the Kwakiutl and of the Trobriand
Islanders should be understood through the ways in which people involved in them
categorise and classify their worlds and interact with each other in terms of
that organization. Walens, in a book called Feasting with Cannibals: An Essay
on Kwakiutl Cosmology (1981), not only reinterprets the ethnographic
information on Kwakiutl social organization and interaction, but also explains
why he considers this essential.
If Walens is correct then to
understand reciprocity and exchange among the Kwakiutl one must take both the
natural and supernatural realms into account. To focus only on exchanges between
human beings in this world would be to miss the determining rationale of those
exchanges. It is not enough to spell out a variety of forms of exchange between
people. Nor is it enough to ‘explain’ exchange relationships by identifying the
kinship relations which determine their form. One must know what underpins the
relationships they perceive between each other. And, among the Kwakiutl, that
requires an understanding of the ways in which they bring together what Western
people would call the natural and supernatural dimensions of existence. A focus
on relationships, without an understanding of the cosmology of the people
involved, will result in a less than adequate understanding of what is going on
for the people involved in them.
Westerners, strongly conditioned to
keep the natural and supernatural separate, and suspicious of the true value of
what is for many an ethereal realm, often display a blindness to metaphysical
understandings in the communities they examine. It is simply ‘not important’ to
explore that dimension of (un)‘reality’. Walens reminds us that this is an
ethnocentric position to adopt. We will miss a great deal if we fail to take
all the understandings of people into account in trying to understand
their way of life. If we focus on what people do but do not research the
why of their behaviour we are very likely to misunderstand the
significance of what we are observing.
Michael Young (1971), in a
description of exchange in a Massim society strongly emphasises the
kinship relations between people and shows how these determine and regulate the
nature of exchanges and interactions between people in Massim society. If you
did not know the kinship relations, you would certainly find both gardening and
Abutu among the Massim very difficult to understand. He also spends time
describing the ritual activity which Massim consider essential to successful
gardening and to the achievement and maintenance of status and rank. There is no
division of the world into natural and supernatural realms. Rather there is one
realm which has both of these dimensions included in it.
The nature of exchange is not nearly
so simple, nor so easily explained, as social exchange theory would suggest.
Although Ockham’s razor suggests that the simplest explanation is usually the
right one, this is only true if you have taken all the relevant information into
account. And, as we have seen, the relevant information can often be invisible
to a person who starts with the assumption that his or her understanding of the
world is the only understanding, or the ‘right’ understanding. Both Walens and
Young show us that an understanding of the nature of reciprocity and exchange is
only possible when the cosmologies of the communities in which they occur are
understood.
Barfield Thomas 1997, The dictionary of anthropology,
Blackwell , Cambridge, Mass.
Boas Franz 1966, Kwakiutl ethnography, Edited by Helen
Codere, University of Chicago Press, Chicago
Damon Frederick H. 1993, Representation and Experience in
Kula and Western Exchange Spheres (or, Billy), Pp. 235-254 in Barry L. Isaac
(ed) Research in Economic Anthropology, Volume 14, JAI Press, Greenwich
Conn.
Emerson, Richard M. 1972a, "Exchange Theory, Part 1: A
Psychological Basis for Social Exchange." Pp. 38-57 in Sociological Theories
in Progress, Vol. 2, edited by Joseph Berger, Morris Zelditch Jr., and Bo
Anderson. Houghton-Mifflin.
Emerson, Richard M. 1972b, "Exchange Theory, Part 2: Exchange
Relations and Networks." Pp. 58-87 in Sociological Theories in Progress,
Vol. 2, edited by Joseph Berger, Morris Zelditch Jr., and Bo Anderson.
Houghton-Mifflin.
Fischer E. and Marek F. (eds) 1973, Marx in His Own
Words (Translator: Anna Bostock) Penguin Books, Harmondsworth
Franklin Sarah and Susan McKinnon 2000, New Directions
in Kinship Study: A Core Concept Revisited, Current Anthropology, Vol. 41
Issue 2 p. 275
Guyer Jane I. 1995, Wealth in People, Wealth in
Things-Introduction, The Journal of African History January, Vol. 36 No.
1 p. 83 ;
Helgason Agnar and Palsson Gisli 1997, Contested Commodities:
The Moral Landscape of Modernist Regimes, Journal of the Royal
Anthropological Institute September Vol. 3 Issue 3 Pp. 451 - 471
Homans George C. 1961, Social Behaviour: Its Elementary
Forms, Routledge and Kegan Paul, London
La Valle Davide 1994, Social exchange and social system: a
Parsonian approach, Sociological Perspectives, Vol. 37 No. 4 pp.
585ff
Lawler Edward J. and Shane R. Thye 1999, Bringing Emotions
Into Social Exchange Theory, Annual Review of Sociology, pp. 217ff
Levi-Strauss Claude 1963, Structural Anthropology,
Basic Books, New York
Malinowski Bronislaw 1977, The Essentials of the Kula, pp.
272 - 6 in I. Rossi, J. Buettner-Janusch & D. Coppenhaver (eds),
Anthropology Full Circle, Praeger, New York
Marx K 1859, A Contribution to the Critique of Political
Economy, http://www.marxists.org/glossary/subject/basic-politics.htm
Molm Linda D., Gretchen Peterson and Nobuyuki Takahashi 2001,
The Value of Exchange, Social Forces, Vol. 80 No. 1 pp. 159ff
Mosko Mark S. 2000, Inalienable Ethnography:
Keeping-While-Giving and the Trobriand Case. (Critique of Annette Weiner),
Journal of the Royal Anthropological Institute, Vol. 6 Issue 3 p. 377
Pannell Sandra 1993, 'Circulating Commodities': Reflections
on the Movement and Meaning of Shells and Stories in North Australia and Eastern
Indonesia, Oceania, September Vol. 64 No. 1 p. 57
Piddocke Stuart 1965, The Potlatch system of the Southern
Kwakiutl: A New Perspective, Southwestern Journal Of Anthropology, Vol.
21 pp. 244-58
Polanyi K. 1977, The Livelihood of Man, Academic
Press, New York
Sahlins M. D., 1972, Stone Age Economics, Aldine
Publishing Co , New York
Thune Carl E. 1983, Kula traders and lineage members: the
structure of village and kula exchange on Normanby Island, pp. 345 – 368 in J.
W. & E. Leach (eds) The Kula: New Perspectives on Massim Exchange,
Cambridge University Press, Cambridge
Toren Christina 1999, Compassion for One Another:
Constituting Kinship as Intentionality in Fiji, Journal of the Royal
Anthropological Institute, Vol. 5 Issue 2 p. 265
Walens Stanley 1981, Feasting with Cannibals: An essay on
Kwakiutl Cosmology, Princeton University Press, Princeton
Whitmeyer Joseph M. 1999, Interest-Network Structures in
Exchange Networks, Sociological Perspectives, Spring Vol. 42 No. 1
p. 23
Young Michael W. 1971, Fighting with food: Leadership,
values and social control in a Massim society, Cambridge University Press,
London
Zafirovski Milan 1998, Socio-Economics and Rational
Choice Theory: Specification of Their Relations, The Journal of
Socio-Economics, Vol. 27 No. 2 Pp.165 - 204
1 See Milan Zafirovski (1998) for a
discussion of the nature of this connection.
2 For a discussion of the nature of
exchange networks, see Whitmeyer Joseph M. 1999, Interest-Network Structures in
Exchange Networks, Sociological Perspectives, Spring Vol. 42 No. 1
p. 23
3 Marxism was extremely influential
through most of the 20th century and still has a strong following.
The Web site http://www.marxists.org/
provides a comprehensive coverage of Marxist writings. For a clear summary of
Marx’s ideas see Fischer E. and Marek F. 1973, Marx in His Own Words
(Translator: Anna Bostock) Penguin Books, Harmondsworth
4 For discussion of the notion of spheres
of exchange, see Guyer Jane I. 1995, Wealth in People, Wealth in
Things-Introduction, The Journal of African History January, Vol. 36 No.
1 p. 83 ; Pannell Sandra 1993, 'Circulating Commodities': Reflections on the
Movement and Meaning of Shells and Stories in North Australia and Eastern
Indonesia, Oceania, September Vol. 64 No. 1 p. 57
5 This is, of course, not the only such
set of relationship possibilities. One can also have, among others, continua of
complementarity, displacement, containment, and accompaniment. The reductionist
enterprise undertaken in social exchange theory strips away and treats as
irrelevant all such multi-dimensional aspects of human
relationships. |